Table of Contents
Send a Letter
Magazine Staff
Back Issues:
 
Departments
Editor's Notes
Letters
Investigations
Chicago Journal
College Report
Class News
Books by Alumni
Deaths
 
 
Citations
For the Record
Center Stage
Chicagophile
 
Alumni Gateway
UofC Homepage
 

Alumni Clubs:

 

 

Economist Judith Chevalier goes down whatever aisles the numbers take her

The GSB professor checks out economic theories in supermarkets, casinos, mutual-fund companies, mergers, and drug firms.

There was a time about five years ago when Graduate School of Business professor Judith Chevalier could name every supermarket in just about any U.S. city. She steeped herself in the prices of packaged goods and carted around loads of data, taking notes while reading the latest Progressive Grocer.

As an industrial organization economist, Chevalier immerses herself in the inner workings of particular industries. And as an applied empirical economist, she does so to see how the ideas of theoretical economists play out in the real world. She scanned supermarket data, for example, to see if that industry’s late-’80s wave of leveraged buyouts—takeovers financed by borrowed funds—could tell her anything about whether capital structure affects product market competition, as some theorists had argued. Chevalier’s real-world investigations showed that there is, in fact, a link: Unleveraged chains tended to expand in those markets where rivals were highly leveraged, and highly leveraged chains charged higher prices.

“Theorists have to sit in offices thinking,” says Chevalier. “I’m more interested in digging around the bowels of Regenstein Library to see what they have on a particular industry. The game is to be clever about finding the right environment to test the theories.”
The 32-year-old Chevalier appears to be playing that game quite shrewdly. In January, she received the American Economic Association’s first Elaine Bennett Research Prize, recognizing outstanding work by young female economists. She holds a Ph.D. in economics from MIT, and, as an undergraduate, won Yale’s Dickerman Prize for best senior thesis in economics. She’s now an associate editor at several academic journals and a faculty research fellow at the National Bureau of Economic Research. This past spring and summer, she published new research on the mutual-fund industry, and she’s gearing up to release papers on theories tested in the real worlds of sports betting, publicly traded companies, pharmaceutical firms, and, once again, supermarket chains.

Chevalier’s insights into the mutual-fund industry made recent headlines in the financial press, which picked up on a June 1999 Journal of Finance paper by Chevalier and MIT’s Glenn Ellison. The economists showed that mutual-fund managers with degrees from more selective schools have systematically higher risk-adjusted rates of return on their investments.

That study was a small but provocative offshoot of a larger May 1999 Quarterly Journal of Economics paper, which began as a general inquiry into how workplace behavior is affected by certain implicit understandings between employers and employees. Though Chevalier and Ellison could have looked at employment relationships in almost any profession, the mutual-fund industry—with its reams of accessible personnel information and trading results—provided the necessary objective measures both of workers’ behavior and of their performance. In their review of the growth and growth-and-income funds tracked by investment-information company Morningstar from 1992 through 1995, Chevalier and Ellison found that younger managers were more likely to lose their jobs than older managers if they performed poorly. This suggested that younger managers would have a strong incentive to make less risky investment decisions, so Chevalier and Ellison investigated further and found that younger managers were indeed more risk-averse than their older counterparts, avoiding not only extremely bad, but also extremely good investment outcomes.

“The paper is a reminder that it’s not just the pay-performance contract that affects employee behavior,” explains Chevalier. “In any job, there’s a set of things that if you do, you’ll get fired, and a set of things that if you do, you’ll get promoted. Most people know where that line is.” That line, she says, “creates incentives that employers need to keep in mind when they write explicit contracts.” Though, she says, as academics “we would tend to shy away from specific recommendations, the idea is to help economists and industry practitioners get some measures of how organizational structure and contracts make people behave.”

Chevalier has since traded the investment houses for a different kind of money-managing scene. Lately, she’s been on the phone with the bookmaker at Las Vegas’s Stardust casino for an October 1999 Journal of Business report. She and Harvard’s Christopher Avery examine asset-valuation theories in what even Chevalier considers a rather unorthodox academic context: football betting. Though they were eager to test the view argued by a number of finance economists that the stock market “overreacts” to news about a company’s prospects, the difference between stock prices and a company’s true value proved too difficult to measure directly. Football betting provided the economists with an analogous but more controlled setting.

Looking at five years of data, Chevalier and Avery followed the change in point spreads in the week before a game. They found that the point spreads moved over the course of the week to favor teams on a hot streak. The bookmakers’ initial estimates of each team’s prospects turned out to be closer to the actual game outcome than the point spread that bettors settled on by the end of the week. In fact, the economists found that betting at the closing line against teams on a hot streak would win some 53 percent of the time. Chevalier and Avery’s observations of point spreads on South Las Vegas Boulevard suggest that overreaction may inflate stock-market prices on Wall Street as well.

Other questions about how and why firms expand, acquire, and merge have taken Chevalier into the arena of publicly traded companies. By the year’s end, she hopes to have completed a report on the investment policies of firms diversifying into new lines of business. She says she takes issue with the suggestion that, following a merger, a company will shift resources from well-performing divisions to struggling ones. The pharmaceutical industry has become yet another lab for Chevalier. For a project on competition, she and GSB colleague Robert Gertner had research assistants spend the summer coding science articles in medical journals. The articles will be used to examine how drug companies’ advertising and pricing respond to news about their products.

And back in the supermarket, Chevalier is analyzing consumer shopping data collected by scanners at Dominick’s Finer Foods stores. With GSB colleagues Peter E. Rossi, MBA’80, PhD’84, and Anil Kashyap, she’s looking at why, for example, stores might put seasonal items like eggnog on sale during the holidays, when consumers are likely to buy them anyway. “It’s puzzling,” she says. “Prices are more countercyclical than you might expect. We don’t know much about this concretely yet. We want to know whether competition is more fierce during these peak shopping periods like holidays, or whether consumers are more price-sensitive when they’re shopping a lot.”

In the past, Chevalier says, colleagues have been skeptical that she would ever get her hands on the right numbers to test the theories that intrigue her. But, so far, she has always surprised them, and, at the very least, she’s always been game.—C.S.
Table of Contents | Send a Letter | Staff | Editor's Notes | Letters | Investigations | Journal | Class News | Books | Deaths