Revolution
from within
WRITTEN BY SHARLA A. STEWART
ILLUSTRATION BY MIRKO ILIC
Print-friendly version
>> continued...
Mirko Ilic |
Ask Mearsheimer
today about perestroika’s progress, and he’s
not even cautiously optimistic. “The only real measure of
how successful perestroika has been is, Are the elite departments
willing to hire qualitative people? Has pressure from perestroika
made elite departments more likely to hire people who don’t
use math? My sense is that it’s had little effect. But,”
he backtracks, “it’s early.” Probably the movement’s
greatest fault, he says, is its tendency to focus too much energy
on APSA and not enough on departments. “Success in the association
and its journal is of limited importance. There’s no question
that APSA matters to the future of political science, and what APSR
publishes has an indirect way of affecting what happens inside departments.
But if members of a department believe a qualitative article—even
if it’s published in APSR—doesn’t count,
then it doesn’t count. One shouldn’t,” he warns,
“underestimate the narrowness of many political scientists
in terms of their intellectual tastes and tolerance for different
approaches.”
Whether or not qualitative researchers
can get jobs is a theme that Mearsheimer sounds repeatedly, and
it’s one that surfaces often on perestroika_glasnost_warmhome,
where graduate students tell of reluctantly incorporating statistical
methodologies into their work in hopes of bettering their odds on
the job market. That wasn’t something Sujatha Fernandes, AM’00,
PhD’03, who in April defended an interpretive dissertation
on the interaction between art and politics in contemporary Cuba,
was willing to do. But that’s also why, although she applied
to major political-science departments, she didn’t expect
or get a call-back. “I never expected to—regardless
of the quality of my work—have a chance against rational-choice
candidates,” says Fernandes, who this fall begins a three-year
Cotsen-Wilson fellowship at Princeton as part of the interdisciplinary
Society of Fellows in the Liberal Arts. Because she and her partner
were job hunting at the same time, she also restricted her search
to major cities, leaving out small liberal-arts colleges, where
she figures an interpretivist is most likely to find a home.
Therein lies the problem, says Mearsheimer.
That qualitative political scientists increasingly take refuge in
small colleges is proof of the discipline’s “economics
envy,” he says. “The major university departments are
important because that’s where the Ph.D.s are produced who
will populate the field over time. If 20 years from now those departments
are filled only with statisticians and mathematicians, the war is
lost.” Perestroikans should pay close attention to the path
that economics, now the most scientific of the social sciences,
has taken. “Economics was once a discipline that promised
a home for qualitative research,” he says. “Now it’s
been driven out.” (Members of the decade-old International
Confederation of Associations for Pluralism in Economics concur.
That group counts among its members “institutionalists, evolutionary
economists, post-Keynesians, economic rhetoricians, systems theorists,
feminists, economic historians, ecological economists, historians
of thought, and political economists”—all united by
their concern that the monolithic dominance of the neoclassical
approach to economics is strangling their discipline.)
The worst thing that could happen,
agrees Chicago political-science professor and department chair
John Brehm, is that departments fracture into “purely quantitative,
philosophical, or qualitative” enclaves. Both Brehm, who does
large-N studies in political psychology and American politics and
is not a perestroikan but believes the movement is good for the
discipline, and Mearsheimer cite the University of Notre Dame’s
economics department, which will split into two departments this
fall, one orthodox (quantitative) graduate program and one, with
no graduate program, for those who focus on economic thought, social
justice, and public policy (heterodox, qualitative stuff). “We
steal from every discipline on the planet—economics, history,
sociology, math, philosophy,” Brehm says, “and it’s
fortunate for the discipline that all these coexist and that the
work is all valued on the same criterion: what it tells us about
politics.” If the two sides of perestroika can’t see
eye-to-eye, says Brehm, it’s not inconceivable that political-science
departments could follow the lead of Notre Dame economics, with
two different sets of standards for tenure review and merit pay
raises.
From outside
political science it’s difficult to conceive any solid
arguments against cultivating the existence of multiple methodologies.
Yet Stanford’s David Laitin, who spent 11 years on Chicago’s
political-science faculty, has come out explicitly against perestroika
and the “hundred flowers blooming” view. In a March
2003 Politics & Society essay, Laitin (whose most recent
work on a theory of political identities uses a rational choice
“tipping model” and large-N statistical analysis to
determine whether Russian-speaking persons in former Soviet states
will learn their nations’ dominant languages) rebukes perestroikans
for having “abandoned the project of a scientific discipline.”
He writes, “It would be convenient to write off this quasi-coordinated
attack on the scientific turn in the study of society, calling its
proponents Luddites. Indeed, their abhorrence of all things mathematical—and
their typical but useless conflation of statistical and formal reasoning—reveals
a fear of the modern.” But even though the movement lacks
“any manifesto offering an alternative view of the discipline,”
he believes it “would be prudent to respond, to defend what
may well be a Sisyphean project in seeking a science of social life.”
(This defense answers perestroikans’ charge that mathematical
political-science research lends itself only to trivial findings.)
Laitin chooses as his “intellectual
target” Making Social Science Matter (Cambridge),
a 2001 book by Danish social scientist Bent Flyvbjerg—not
a perestroikan, but who, Laitin says, captures many of perestroika’s
core themes. Flyvbjerg, for example, argues that social sciences’
strength lies not in scientific sophistication but in its rich,
reflexive analysis of values and power, which he sees as essential
to a society’s social and economic development. He calls this
reflexive approach “phronesis,” which Laitin equates
with the narrative social scientists discover through fieldwork.
Yet narrative, Laitin argues, cannot stand alone—it relies
too heavily on one person’s interpretation and tends to disregard
otherwise counterintuitive facts that can be found only by systematically
studying a large number of cases on similar variables. In place
of a hundred flowers, Laitin believes political science should cultivate
a single hybrid methodology, a three-part approach that begins with
fieldwork and narrative, then tests with statistics and formal reasoning.
Laitin also calls for aggressively
weeding the garden of research that lacks scientific validity. “[I]f
theoretical logic or scientific evidence finds a theory or procedure
to be fallacious,” he writes, “that procedure’s
flower bed should no longer be cultivated within the discipline
in which it was originally seeded.” In particular Laitin attacks
qualitative case studies. Because they select “on the dependent
variable,” he says, they “will ultimately lead to faulty
inferences about causation.” And he refutes Mearsheimer’s
call for diverse departments: “It would be a warping of the
scientific frame if we built into the charter of any department
of political science that there had to be an expert in ‘realism,’
or in ‘South Asia,’ or in ‘democracy,’ or
in ‘qualitative methods.’” In an e-mail conversation
Laitin says the bottom line is that he believes in scientific progress.
“I’ve worked assiduously at learning new methods when
they better help political scientists answer important questions.”
Laitin’s belief that not all
methodologies are created equal certainly seems reasonable. Within
perestroika a similar red flag has been raised by UC–Irvine’s
Kristen Renwick Monroe, a political theorist who once crunched numbers
with the best of them, studying econometrics under Nobelists George
Stigler and Robert Fogel. Her current work focuses on altruism:
why, for example, some people risked rescuing Jews during the Holocaust,
a project for which she ditched formal survey methodology for copious
informal interviews. “One thing perestroika hasn’t fully
addressed is that some techniques are better than others,”
she says. “Simply advocating for methodological pluralism
is not enough. We need some agreed-upon standards.” Monroe
offers a medical metaphor: “We would expect a cancer specialist
to tell us which of our treatment options are more likely to lead
to recovery. Going down to Mexico and eating lots of apricots is
probably not as valid an option as drug therapy.” There’s
no reason, she says, that political scientists can’t expect
the same rigorous evaluation of methods.
The dilemma, of course, is that
political scientists who don’t use hard science may find their
work dismissed by rational-choice scholars and statistical modelers
before it even reaches the standards test. That’s why Monroe
and other perestroikans would like to redraw the lines of debate.
“This whole dichotomy between quantitative and qualitative
work is misleading,” she says. Susanne Rudolph calls for a
discipline that’s problem- rather than method-driven. “I
try to imagine a science and an association that is safe for intellectual
border crossers,” she said at the 2001 APSA meeting. “People
who work on the border are apt to acquire a conceptual creole.”
Border-crossers are also open to discovering which method best fits
the problem at hand, adds Monroe, rather than deeming at the outset
certain methodologies to be superior for their scientific validity.
A problem-driven approach requires
not merely open-mindedness, Monroe emphasizes, but also humility.
“If our best ideas of yesterday can be shown to be wrong,
given better data or improved techniques of analysis,” she
says, “then so can our ideas of today. Modesty and science
make good bedfellows.” The problem with Laitin’s single,
hybrid methodology, she continues, is that it’s “still
too imperialistic. It presumes that it will answer all questions
raised by a problem and that other methods won’t, when that’s
something we can’t really know.” At work on editing
Perestroika, Methodological Pluralism, Governance, and Diversity
in Contemporary Political Science, due from Yale in 2005, she
remains optimistic about what perestroika will bring for the discipline.
“The issue of science and what we mean by science is on the
table in a way that it wasn’t five years ago,” Monroe
says. “There are more conversations in departments. Certainly
there’s more entrenchment, but there’s also heightened
awareness.”
And heightened awareness, the hope
goes, will translate into better scholarship over the long run—which,
says Mearsheimer, has implications far beyond cluttered professorial
offices and cliquish journal review boards. “The work that
political scientists do should have an impact on how people outside
the discipline think about the world,” he says. “We
study important political problems. It’s hard to predict who
or which approach will give the best understanding of a problem—important
political insights come from all kinds of people and all kinds of
approaches. The best thing to do is to create is an environment
where scholars can use all kinds of approaches, even conflicting
ones, and let them go at it.”
Ever the realist, he’s
quick to add that whether that will happen remains to be seen.
|
|