Investigations
Acting globally, thinking
locally
Gone are the giddy days of globalization. Domino-effect
market failures like 1998’s “Asian flu” and the
September 11, 2001, terrorist attacks emphasize that rather than
one happy village busily churning out prosperity, the globalized
world is a network of sometimes painful connections. As Marvin Zonis,
Dan Lefkovitz, and Sam Wilkin put it in The Kimchi Matters:
Global Business and Local Politics in a Crisis-Driven World,
(Agate, 2003), by the time those crises hit, the “party had
gone on too long. Globalization’s heightened intimacies became
increasingly uncomfortable, as many of the guests turned out to
be angry, unpredictable, duplicitous, or violent.”
For the most part, such a turn of events went
unheralded by global forecasters even as the 1990s international
trade boom brought distant countries and their idiosyncratic governments
into closer contact. Though globalization amplified and exported
the regional problems of dysfunctional states, Western policy makers,
investors, and corporate leaders were blinded by a vision of “peace
through commerce” and failed to pay heed to the local politics
that eventually triggered global catastrophes. So say Zonis, a GSB
international political-economy professor and head of political-risk
consultancy Marvin Zonis & Associates; Lefkovitz, AM’98,
a freelance country analyzer at Zonis; and Wilkin, AM’97,
a country risk adviser at Aon Trade Credit.
According to Kimchi Matters, the international
community is contingent on the behavior of individual nations. As
evidence the authors present a smorgasbord of regional processes
and problems from countries around the world. They call these vital,
often overlooked local conditions “kimchi,” after a
spicy pickled-cabbage dish popular in (and, for the most part, only
in) Korea. “Today,” they explain, “almost everyone
eats Big Macs,” evidence of the global-village side of globalization.
“But kimchi matters more than ever before.”
To illustrate how local obstacles can sideswipe
international Goliaths, the authors offer Bill Gates’s initial
foray into the Korean market. In 1998 Microsoft planned to invest
$20 million in Hangul & Computer, and in exchange the South
Korean software company would stop producing its Korean-language
word-processing program, surrendering its near monopoly to Microsoft.
But news of the deal brought a national backlash—fueled by
antiforeign sentiment and national reverence for the Korean alphabet—and
Hangul & Computer was forced to abandon the deal. “In
short,” the book explains, “Microsoft’s expansion
strategy had inadvertently triggered a political opposition movement.”
Investors and policy makers can avoid such missteps,
the authors argue, by asking not only whether a country is stable
but also how its stability is produced. They provide a simple model
for local political dynamics: A demand by the public requires the
government to react. Although a competent response satisfies the
populace, an incompetent reaction engenders more extreme demands,
which, in turn, generate another government response. This cycle
can eventually trigger a political crisis.
In the Philippines, for example, President Ferdinand
Marcos’s 1969 reelection coincided with a bad monsoon season
and a violent Communist guerrilla uprising. “Though none of
this was really the president’s fault,” the authors
note, opposition grew. Marcos reacted by faking assassination attempts
and terror attacks and then declaring martial law, crushing dissent
and granting himself sweeping authority. To maintain power, he built
a regime of corruption and patronage, which inhibited legitimate
business, angered the middle class, and strengthened the opposition.
When rival politicians were killed, discontent mounted, and Marcos
was forced from office, leaving foreign businesses with Philippine
investments tangled in criminal misconduct allegations.
But things might have turned out differently.
Popular dissatisfaction of any source can be channeled in many ways,
the writers argue, offering several examples. Zimbabwe’s Robert
Mugabe managed national discontent by blaming his country’s
problems on South Africa and England. India, though plagued by poverty,
has dozens of political parties and holds relatively free and fair
elections. And Singapore, while curtailing free speech and civil
rights, heads off discontent with economic growth and stability.
Each of those governmental responses is intimately
related to what Kimchi Matters terms “the ruling
bargain.” Submitting to authority, the authors argue, is onerous:
taxes must be paid, laws obeyed, and other intrusions (in an extreme
case, conscription into a national army) accepted. In exchange governments
earn the public’s support by promoting economic prosperity,
physical security, and common defense. But each country formulates
a unique bargain and justifies its authority—creating legitimacy—through
different techniques. Autocratic nations rely on charismatic leaders
to charm or terrorize the populace; democratic governments earn
authority by representing the people; and in “developmental
states” such as Singapore authority is earned by “delivering
the goods—usually stability and prosperity.”
While a government’s structure may dictate
its success in abating popular discontent, in some cases that structure
is so attenuated that the task is assumed solely by a country’s
leader. In Uganda policies depend almost entirely on the president,
now Yoweri Museveni, who has reduced poverty and AIDS but also has
banned political parties and activities. The authors stress, however,
that “leadership is only part of the story.” Some countries
have strong enough institutions that they can essentially run themselves.
During “Monicagate,” for instance, crime fell, the economy
grew, and “the American government continued to function effectively
regardless of its rather distracted leadership.” Governments
that have developed a self-perpetuating, responsive system are the
most stable, the most likely to avert potential crises, and the
best equipped to generate prosperity.
Even with a strong system, however, individual
policies make or break stability, and political pressures can sometimes
push policy makers in the wrong direction. When a leader faces reelection,
for example, he or she often abandons policies that call for short-term
sacrifices but create long-term benefits in favor of ones that create
short-term economic booms, though they may ultimately cause a crash.
This pattern clearly has emerged in Mexico, which has seen economic
turmoil every six years—the length of the election cycle—since
1976. Likewise, entrenched interests can hinder development. Brazil’s
constitution specifies rights for nearly every special-interest
group, preserving privileges, such as government pension programs
that cost tens of billions of dollars, at the expense of the larger
good. Thus particular political circumstances can inadvertently
reduce a nation’s economic potential.
The authors concede, however, that not
everything is a local matter: “No country is an island, even
when it comes to its own stability.” Of course, that is globalization’s
lesson: a country’s particular politics and economics will
inevitably influence and be influenced by world events. But, the
authors admonish, “‘One size fits all’ solutions
do not work.” Each country still harbors its own kimchi beneath
globalization’s golden arches, so for the sake of peace and
profit, the world’s businesses, investors, and politicians
must be ever more sensible to local flavors.—A.L.M.
|
|